Rents, resources, and regulators: Mapping the political economy of corruption in Ghana’s extractive sector

0

By Felix Larry Essilfie (Dr)

In the intricate tapestry of Ghana’s political economy, the extractive sector occupies a paradoxical position: a beacon of national wealth and a crucible of institutional erosion.

Despite democratic consolidation and recurrent reformist rhetoric, Ghana remains mired in patterns of rent-seeking, fiscal populism, and regulatory capture that are disturbingly emblematic of the broader “resource curse” phenomenon theorized by development economists.

Far from breaking the historical curse of resource-rich underperformance, Ghana’s political institutions have largely adapted to extractive wealth by internalizing its distortive incentives, illustrating the resilience of neopatrimonial logics within democratic façades.

The theoretical underpinnings of this malaise are neither new nor surprising. Resource curse theory, long championed by Auty (1993) and Sachs and Warner (2001), predicts that natural wealth, rather than serving as a springboard for diversified growth, often undermines institutional quality and fosters governance pathologies.

Ghana’s gold and petroleum sectors reveal the mechanics of this curse vividly: extractive rents have not only entrenched elite privilege but have also induced macro-fiscal volatility, weakened public financial management, and eroded the legitimacy of democratic oversight mechanisms.

Empirical evidence, such as the USD 2.1 billion in fiscal leakages recorded in the gold sector between 2015 and 2020, underscores the scale of rent extraction and the corrosive impact of illicit financial flows (IFFs) on national development prospects.

Yet Ghana’s political economy of extraction cannot be fully comprehended through resource curse theory alone. Rentier state theory (Mahdavy, 1970; Beblawi and Luciani, 1987) provides a complementary lens, illuminating how political coalitions in resource-dependent states optimize for control over rents rather than fostering productive capacity.

Although Ghana boasts a competitive electoral system, the underlying logic of rent distribution remains quintessentially rentier: ruling coalitions leverage resource revenues not to invest in public goods but to stabilize political loyalties through clientelistic networks, discretionary spending, and informal institutional arrangements.

The state thus becomes less an agent of development and more a mechanism for rent allocation—a dynamic reinforced, rather than mitigated, by periodic political turnover.

Critical to this dynamic is the nature of Ghana’s institutional architecture. Drawing from North, Wallis, and Weingast’s (2009) concept of “limited access orders,” Ghana’s regulatory environment exemplifies how elite coalitions systematically control access to economic opportunities as a strategy of political survival.

Regulatory bodies such as the Minerals Commission and the Petroleum Commission, ostensibly established to depoliticize and professionalize resource governance, have become sites of political contestation and collusion.

Personnel changes following elections, regulatory forbearance toward politically connected firms, and the discretionary allocation of mining licenses all reflect an equilibrium in which regulatory independence is structurally subordinated to rentier imperatives.

This institutional capture is not without profound macroeconomic consequences. Revenue shortfalls resulting from illicit flows and tax avoidance in the extractive sector have amplified Ghana’s fiscal deficits, necessitating repeated Eurobond issuances (notably in 2018 and 2021) and heightening external debt vulnerabilities.

The chronic overestimation of extractive revenue projections—by 15–20% relative to actual outturns over the past decade—has undermined budget credibility, triggered mid-year fiscal adjustments, and worsened expenditure arrears.

Consequently, Ghana’s public financial management system operates under conditions of permanent fragility, structurally tethered to the vagaries of commodity price cycles and elite rent-extraction imperatives.

Political economists examining Ghana’s trajectory must thus grapple with a fundamental paradox: democratic institutions coexist with pervasive neopatrimonial governance patterns.

Competitive elections, rather than displacing rentier dynamics, have recalibrated them, incentivizing short-term resource appropriation to finance electoral cycles and cement political coalitions.

Regulatory agencies, despite formal autonomy, are enmeshed in elite bargaining processes that subordinate technocratic objectives to political exigencies.

The result is an extractive sector governance framework that is neither transparently accountable nor entirely predatory—occupying a fragile liminal space that leaves Ghana acutely vulnerable to external shocks, fiscal crises, and developmental stagnation.

Comparatively, Ghana’s experience offers a sobering midpoint between the predatory rentierism of Nigeria and Angola and the institutionalized prudence of Botswana.

While Ghana avoids the extremes of authoritarian plunder, it equally falls short of embedding extractive wealth into a sustainable development framework.

Botswana’s success with the Pula Fund and institutionalized savings mechanisms remains elusive in Ghana, where stabilization funds such as the Ghana Stabilization Fund suffer from political encroachments, ad hoc withdrawals, and ambiguous fiscal rules.

Policy remedies to this entrenched malaise must be both technically sound and politically realistic.

Institutional strengthening efforts must prioritize insulating regulatory appointments from political interference, perhaps through tenure protection clauses, transparent nomination procedures, and strengthened parliamentary oversight mechanisms.

Revenue transparency reforms, such as mandatory contract disclosure and the establishment of comprehensive beneficial ownership registries, could help illuminate the opaque networks through which rent extraction occurs.

More ambitiously, restructuring elite bargains to reward developmental performance—linking long-term political survival to measurable governance outcomes—offers a fragile but necessary pathway toward recalibrating incentive structures.

However, technical fixes alone are insufficient absent broader shifts in political economy dynamics.

Civic empowerment, sustained media scrutiny, and robust civil society mobilization around resource governance issues are essential to disrupt the equilibrium of elite collusion.

Embedding extractive wealth into a developmental bargain with citizens, rather than treating it as a private fiefdom of political elites, remains the ultimate test of Ghana’s democratic maturity.

Absent decisive reform, Ghana risks perpetuating the paradox of a “democratic rentier state”—one where electoral competition masks but does not transform the deep structures of rentier extraction and institutional decay.

The stakes are existential: for Ghana’s extractive resources to serve as foundations of prosperity rather than vectors of corruption, a comprehensive, politically smart, and technically grounded governance transformation must be urgently pursued.

The choice confronting Ghana is thus stark: either sever the symbiotic relationship between rents and regulators or remain ensnared in a political economy where wealth deepens rather than resolves structural poverty and democratic disillusionment.

The author is the Executive Director, IDER