Dani Rodrik weighs in on protectionism, development, redistribution and more

0

Project Syndicate: “What some decry as protectionism and mercantilism,” you wrote last month, “is really a rebalancing toward addressing important national issues.” As you explain in your 2017 book, Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy, “The blind promotion of unbridled globalisation was never good economics.” What forgotten or neglected principles has mainstream economics re-embraced (or reconsidered) recently, and are there major ones that economists are still ignoring?

Dani Rodrik: The main thing we forgot, funnily enough, was that economics is the science of trade-offs. Squeezing ever-more gains from ever-deeper trade and financial integration came at a cost: many communities and workers saw their economic well-being deteriorate, and vital global public goods, such as the climate and public health, were neglected. If one raised objections, the overwhelming response was, “We can have it all: let trade be free, and we will deal with any issue it creates using targetted remedies such as compensation and carbon taxes”. This brings us to the second forgotten economic principle: the principle of second-best. The world is necessarily second-best, and our policy objectives are not as neatly separable as first-best economists assumed.

PS: You have also noted that US President Joe Biden’s “industrial policies, green subsidies, and made-in-America provisions” are a “source of irritation” and indeed “worry” for the developing world. Given this new global context, what should developing countries be doing to make progress toward an economic model that is more reliant on “service industries and small and medium-size enterprises, rather than on industrial exports?



DR: The kind of development model you mention is not one with which we have much experience. So, this is a very tough question. That said, I really do not see much alternative to finding the answer.

The central challenge for developing countries is determining how to get their people into more productive occupations. For the longest time, the prescription was to promote industrialisation. But manufacturing – especially the kind that is internationally competitive and plugged into global value chains – no longer absorbs much labour. So, we need to support growth in smaller and medium-size enterprises, mostly in services, by providing them with a set of public inputs such as management training, access to technology, specialised skills, better regulatory structures and access to credit. Success will require a new policy mindset and a lot of experimentation with different approaches.

PS: You have warned that the narrative underpinning a new “healthier” form of globalisation and the industrial and other policies it entails must not be “hijacked” by leading powers’ national-security establishments. Mismanagement of the US-China rivalry, in particular, threatens to make the global economy “inhospitable”. Which current and potential US and Chinese policies pose the biggest risks on this front, and how can economists persuade policymakers to adopt a “productivist” rather than a “hyper-realist” paradigm?

DR: I think the greatest risk on the Chinese side would be an invasion of Taiwan. The status quo on this issue has worked well, and I hope both China and the United States will preserve it.

On the American side, I like National Security Adviser Jake Sullivan’s “small yard, high fence” policy, which limits Chinese access to a limited range of technologies that are critical to national security. The danger is that the yard will expand over time, and commercial relations with China will turn into a zero-sum game.

On the second question – how economists can push policymakers to engage in productivist policies – I am not sure, frankly, that economists have this kind of influence. I suspect that policymakers and policy entrepreneurs will lead the way, and economists will follow.

By the Way…

PS: Policy prescriptions for managing the negative effects of globalisation have often emphasised redistribution, together with interventions like education and skills upgrading. But you have argued that redistribution is inadequate to offset the inequality-enhancing effects of hyper-globalisation. Why is that, and how should we think about the role of redistribution in making globalisation fit for purpose?

DR: There are two aspects to this. First, while redistribution and compensation may be more desirable on traditional economic grounds, they don’t work well in practice. There are a few reasons for this. For one thing, these policies create their own inefficiencies. For another, the net gains from additional trade liberalisation are often not large enough to support meaningful real-world redistribution. There is also a credibility problem: we would like to promise the losers compensation, but they have good reason to doubt that it will ever arrive. In the US, for example, trade-adjustment assistance programmes have often been underfinanced.

The second aspect is that when people lose their jobs, they lose more than just their income; and the damage to their communities and social lives cannot be fixed with a cheque. Any meaningful adjustment to economic change requires the creation of good jobs in other sectors, and this is not addressed by redistribution.

PS: “As trade agreements become less about tariffs and non-tariff barriers at the border and more about domestic rules and regulations,” you have written, “they become more likely to produce purely redistributive outcomes.” What qualifies as a well-designed trade agreement? How can such agreements “result in the global upgrading of regulations and standards”, such as for labour and the environment?

DR: I am more a fan of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade model, with tariff liberalisation among major trading partners and the benefits extended to poorer countries through “most-favoured nation” treatment. Many arrangements concerning intellectual property rights or services, designed under the auspices of the World Trade Organisation or embodied in regional free-trade agreements, are overreach.

 

I do not think that trade agreements per se can be used to achieve a global upgrading of standards in non-trade areas such as labour or the environment. Using trade as a wedge to get governments to clean up the environment and treat their workers better is ineffective and creates all kinds of distortions. If governments are serious about protecting labour and the environment, they should strike real deals in their proper fora – say, giving the International Labour Organisation teeth or making binding environmental commitments.

PS: The International Economic Association, of which you are president, has embarked on a multi-year, global project to enhance the role of women in the economics profession. What steps is the IEA taking to advance this goal? Do you view greater diversity as a remedy to some of the profession’s aforementioned failings?

DR: One of the ways we can make the economics profession better – by which I mean not only more inclusive, but also better equipped to address the real problems of the world economy – is to make sure that it reflects the voices of a diverse set of scholars. At present women economists from developing countries face high barriers, owing not only to local practices and norms but also lack of access to networks in centres of economics research. The IEA’s Women in Leadership in Economics Initiative (IEA-WE) is a relatively small but still meaningful (I hope) step toward addressing this problem.

We are doing several things to drive progress. We are undertaking both quantitative and qualitative research on the prospects for women economists in several developing economies. We are supporting research on specific interventions that can help women overcome barriers in the profession. And we are trying to amplify women’s voices in the global public sphere through partnerships with global platforms, including Project Syndicate. I am very proud of this initiative, which is led by Ashwini Deshpande. Raquel Fernández, Fiona Tregenna, María Inés Berniell and I serve as team members.

Read More

Against the World: Anti-Globalism and Mass Politics Between the World Wars

By Tara Zahra

This excellent and highly readable book demonstrates the various forms the backlash to economic globalisation takes, from nationalism to an emphasis on domestically produced clothing. The focus is on the interwar period, and the story is told through the experiences of particular individuals. Covering material that is not particularly well-known to economists and other contemporary experts, this book sheds light on our current era of discontent with globalisation.

Power and Progress: Our Thousand-Year Struggle Over Technology and Prosperity

By Daron Acemoglu and Simon Johnson

In this important book, Acemoglu and Johnson place technology in its proper context. On one hand, it is a source of prosperity; on the other, it often leaves many people behind. Societies can shape how technology evolves and push it in a more positive direction. I doubt everyone will read this cover to cover – but even if you don’t, its message is clear and, as we ponder the future of artificial intelligence, hugely important.

Underground Empire: How America Weaponised the World Economy

By Henry Farrell and Abraham Newman

The world economy, from finance to technology, runs on networks. Those at the centre of the networks control – often subtly and invisibly – what happens within them. More often than not, it is the US which has had that privilege. Anyone who wants to understand how the world economy got to where it is today, and how it will probably evolve, should read this book.

By a PS Contributor

I wrote Straight Talk on Trade as a punchy, readable exposition of my views on what we are doing right and wrong, and how we can fix the problems in the world economy. The book came out before the unravelling of hyper-globalisation, so it presages many of the debates we are having today about how to move forward. In particular, I present an argument for rebalancing the needs of global markets and those of national economies in a way that is more sensitive to the requirements of sustainable development and economic inclusion.

I also take a few swipes at the economics profession for its often-doctrinaire position on the role of markets and government regulation. Economists, I argue, should take more seriously a key insight of their own models: understanding context – making the right assumptions about the underlying constraints and structure – is key to good economics and policy guidance.

Dani Rodrik, Professor of International Political Economy at Harvard Kennedy School, is President of the International Economic Association and the author of Straight Talk on Trade: Ideas for a Sane World Economy (Princeton University Press, 2017).

Copyright: Project Syndicate, 2023.
www.project-syndicate.org

              

Leave a Reply